05807nam 2201345 a 450 991045679520332120200520144314.01-283-16374-897866131637451-4008-3680-810.1515/9781400836802(CKB)2550000000040079(EBL)729947(OCoLC)741492620(SSID)ssj0000521104(PQKBManifestationID)11372113(PQKBTitleCode)TC0000521104(PQKBWorkID)10514683(PQKB)10127613(MiAaPQ)EBC729947(StDuBDS)EDZ0000406744(OCoLC)744350495(MdBmJHUP)muse36867(DE-B1597)446843(OCoLC)979629301(DE-B1597)9781400836802(Au-PeEL)EBL729947(CaPaEBR)ebr10482000(CaONFJC)MIL316374(EXLCZ)99255000000004007920101119d2011 uy 0engur|n|---|||||txtccrA behavioral theory of elections[electronic resource] /Jonathan Bendor ... [et al.]Course BookPrinceton, N.J. Princeton University Pressc20111 online resource (264 p.)Description based upon print version of record.0-691-13506-1 0-691-13507-X Includes bibliographical references and index. Frontmatter -- Contents -- Acknowledgments -- Chapter One. Bounded Rationality and Elections -- Chapter Two. Aspiration-based Adaptive Rules -- Chapter Three. Party Competition -- Chapter Four. Turnout -- Chapter Five. Voter Choice -- Chapter Six. An Integrated Model of Two-Party Elections -- Chapter Seven. Elections with Multiple Parties -- Chapter Eight. Conclusions: Bounded Rationality and Elections -- Appendix A. Proofs -- Appendix B. The Computational Model -- Bibliography -- IndexMost theories of elections assume that voters and political actors are fully rational. While these formulations produce many insights, they also generate anomalies--most famously, about turnout. The rise of behavioral economics has posed new challenges to the premise of rationality. This groundbreaking book provides a behavioral theory of elections based on the notion that all actors--politicians as well as voters--are only boundedly rational. The theory posits learning via trial and error: actions that surpass an actor's aspiration level are more likely to be used in the future, while those that fall short are less likely to be tried later. Based on this idea of adaptation, the authors construct formal models of party competition, turnout, and voters' choices of candidates. These models predict substantial turnout levels, voters sorting into parties, and winning parties adopting centrist platforms. In multiparty elections, voters are able to coordinate vote choices on majority-preferred candidates, while all candidates garner significant vote shares. Overall, the behavioral theory and its models produce macroimplications consistent with the data on elections, and they use plausible microassumptions about the cognitive capacities of politicians and voters. A computational model accompanies the book and can be used as a tool for further research.ElectionsVotingPsychological aspectsBehaviorism (Political science)Electronic books.Condorcet winner.Downsian party competition.Duverger's Law.Markov chain.Pareto dominance.adaptation.aspiration-based adaptation.aspiration-based adaptive rule.aspiration-based adjustment.aspirations.bandwagon effect.behavior.behavioral theory.bounded rationality.candidates.computational model.decision making.election voting.elections.equilibrium behavior.faction size.framing.game-theoretic model.hedonics.heuristics.incumbent.majority faction.multiparty elections.parties.party affiliation.party competition.payoffs.platforms.political parties.politicians.population size.propensity.rational choice theory.rational choice.rationality.retrospective voting.satisficing.search behavior.stochastic process.turnout.two-party elections.voter choice.voter coordination.voter participation.voter turnout.voters.Elections.VotingPsychological aspects.Behaviorism (Political science)324.9001/9Bendor Jonathan B1049314Diermeier Daniel, authttp://id.loc.gov/vocabulary/relators/autSiegel David A., authttp://id.loc.gov/vocabulary/relators/autMiAaPQMiAaPQMiAaPQBOOK9910456795203321A behavioral theory of elections2478210UNINA